ExecutiveSummary
Global food prices nearly doubled during 200408 and have remained
relativelyhighsincethen.Mostrecently,theFAOindexofrealglobalfood
pricesrosefrom151pointsinJune2009to172pointsinJanuary2010.Therise in global
food prices was highest for cereals, which remain relatively
expensive:between2005and2008theinternationalpriceofwheatmorethan
doubled,andglobalriceandmaizepricestripled,andasofJune2009,wheat
andmaizepricesremainedsubstantiallyhigherthanfouryearspreviously(by
respectively55percentand87percent)whilericepriceswereaboutdouble.
Anumberofsimultaneouseventsexplaintheunusuallyhighfoodprice inflation
that took place during 200708. While supply constraints ( in particular low
levels of world cereal stocks) played a role, the main drivers were increases
in demand (especially the rapid increase in the use of food
cropstoproducebiofuels),speculation(largeflowsofspeculativecapitalinto
agriculturalcommodityfuturesmarkets)andpolicyfailures(especiallyexport
restrictions).
InSouthAsia,foodpriceinflationvariedsignificantlyamongcountries.
In200708,itrangedfromrelativelymoderateinIndia(about7percent),to high in
Nepal and Bangladesh (about 15 percent), to very high in Pakistan (
around20percent)andinSriLankaandAfghanistan(morethan30percent). Besidestheintercountryvariations,thereweresignificantvariationsamong
commoditiesand,inmanycountries,amongregions.
Food price inflation exceeded nonfood price inflation throughout South
Asia except in India. During the 200708 food crisis, food price inflation
became the main driver of general inflation throughout of most
SouthAsia.Thoughinthesecondhalfof2008,theroleoffoodpriceincreases diminished in
most countries of the region after prices came down, in 2010 foodpricesagainbecamethemainfactordrivinggeneralinflationinanumber
ofcountriesincludingIndia.
South Asian
countries responded to food price inflation with a wide range of policies and
measures.Attheheartoffoodpricepoliciesinthe region is the political economy
of the tradeoff between consumers’ and producers’interests.Mostofthemeasuresthatweretakensoughttodampen
the negative effects of the food price rises on consumer welfare, and were
shortterm in nature; measures to address traditional constraints on
agriculturalproduction,ortootherwisefacilitateasupplyresponse,havebeen
muchlesscommon.Mostpopularhavebeentradepolicymeasurestodampen
priceincreases(e.g.abolishingimporttariffs)ortoensureadequatesupplies
ondomesticmarkets(e.g.restrictingexports);buildinguporexpandingpublic grain
reserves; controlling prices; and extending existing social protection measures
or (to a much lesser extent) introducing new social protection programs.
IMPACTOFFOODPRICEINFLATIONONTHEPOOR
Besides negatively affecting
macroeconomic stability, food price inflation
decreasesthewelfareofhouseholdswhoarenetbuyers,ratherthansellers,of food. In
particular, it threatens the welfare of poorer households, for whom
foodtakesalargeshareoftotalspending.
InSouthAsiamosthouseholds,includingthoselivinginruralareas,are
netbuyersoffoodandlikelytosufferwelfarelossesfromincreasesin foodprices.Asiswellknown,thevastmajorityofurbanhouseholdsarenet
food buyers. But contrary to popular perception, 70 80 percent of rural households in the region
are also net buyers of the main grain staples ( rice and/orwheat) .
FortheaveragehouseholdinSouthAsia,foodtakesclosetohalfoftotal
spending, compared to only 17 percent in the United States. This high
percentage makes South Asian populations very vulnerable to food price
increases.
Poor people are
likely to have been especially hardhit by high food prices.First,poorpeoplespendalargerproportionoftheirincomeonfood.
Second,thefoodpriceinflationof200708wasespeciallystarkforcereals,and
theproportionofcerealsintotalfoodspendingismuchhigherforthepoor
thanthenonpoor.Moreover,householdswhopreviouslywerelivingnotfar above the
poverty line are likely to have fallen into poverty as the result of
higherfoodprices.
Theeffectoffoodpriceinflationonhouseholdwelfareisanalyzedat
twolevelsinChapter2.Thefirst,simpler,levelkeepsquantitiesfixedandis limited
to the pure firstorder impact of the price change. Households are
classifiedintonetbuyersandnetsellersofacommoditywherethelattergain
andtheformersufferwelfarelossesasaresultofapriceincrease.Asecond levelofanalysistakesaccountoftheconsumptionandproductiondecisions
that take place as a result of the price change. We use nationally
representative household survey data for Bangladesh, Pakistan, and Nepal
frombeforethefoodcrisistosimulatetheimpactoffoodpriceinflationon poverty
headcount levels, taking account of both firstround and second
roundeffects.Theanalysisdoesnotallowforgeneralequilibriumeffects.
In Bangladesh, Pakistan, and Nepal, the net marketing position of
householdsleadstosignificantfirstroundwelfarelossesforthelarge majority of
households. In Bangladesh and Nepal respectively, about 80
percentand70percentofhouseholdsarenetbuyersofrice,whileinPakistan
77percentofhouseholdsarenetbuyersofwheat.Basedonfirstroundeffects
only(netbuyernetselleranalysis)a50percentincreaseinthepriceofrice would raise
the national poverty headcount ratio in Bangladesh by about 6 percentage points. Similarly, a 40 percent
increase in the wheat price in
Pakistanwouldcausea2percentagepointincreaseinnationalpoverty.The
estimatedpovertyeffectinPakistanissmallerthaninBangladeshbecauseof the lower
price increase and the smaller average gap between household consumptionandproduction.InNepal,a20percentincreaseinthericeprice
would raise the national poverty headcount ratio by only 0.5 percentage points,
but rising rice prices make households who are already poor even poorer. In all
three countries the impact of food price inflation on poverty
differssignificantlyamongregions,andregionalpovertyimpactsoftengreatly
exceedtheaveragenationalimpact.
In all three countries, secondround responses in production and
consumption are found to offset part of the welfare loss from first round
effects. In Bangladesh, based on differences in national poverty headcount
ratios with and without secondround effects, adjustments in
behaviorbyconsumersandproducersdecreasethefirstorderpovertyimpact by about 2
percentage points or up to 30 percent in proportional terms. In
Pakistan,thesecondroundresponseshaveanevenlargereffect;theyreverse
upto90percentofthefirstroundimpactonthepovertyheadcount.
InSriLanka,foodpriceinflationislikelytohaveincreasedthepoverty
headcountratioandtohavebeenparticularlyharmfultothepoorestof the poor.
Analysis by the World Bank shows that a large share of the
populationwasclusteredaroundthepovertylineevenbeforethefoodcrisis,
andimpliesthata10percentdeclineinpercapitaconsumptionmayleadtoa 6 percentage
point increase in the poverty headcount ratio. In Afghanistan,
thereisnoinformationregardingthepovertyimpactoffoodpriceinflation,
butbecauseevenbeforethefoodcrisis42percentoftheAfghanpopulation
wasclassifiedaspoor,andanestimated20percentofthepopulationlivedjust above the
poverty line, there is no doubt that the impact of the food price
crisisinAfghanistanhasbeenextremelyserious.InIndia,existingprograms
andpoliciesmadethatcountryrelativelyshockprooftothefoodcrisis.
The firstround welfare loss caused by higher food prices is larger in urban
areas than in rural. Unlike most urban consumers who can only respond on
the consumption side, most rural households can adjust both
consumptionandproduction.InBangladeshtheheadcountratiobasedonthe upper poverty
line increases by about 6 percentage points in urban areas compared to 5
percentage points in rural areas. In Pakistan the urbanrural
disparityisevenlarger:theurbanheadcountratioincreasesby3percentage points while
the rural ratio increases by less than one percentage point. In Nepalthedisparitybetweenruralandurbanareasislesspronounced,because
ofthesmalleroverallimpactofhigherfoodprices.
Theimpactoffoodpriceincreasesonthepovertyheadcountalsovaries
considerablyamonghouseholdsindifferentincomegroups.Bangladesh
andPakistanbothhavehighconcentrationsofhouseholdsaroundthepoverty
line.Asaresultmostofthewelfarelossfromhighfoodpricesisconcentrated
amonghouseholdsinthemiddleofthedistributionofpercapitaexpenditures. In
Bangladesh the firstround impact of higher food prices on the poverty
headcountratiointhethirdexpenditurequintileis24percentagepointsusing the
country’s upper poverty line and 34 percentage points using the lower
povertyline.Similarly,inPakistanthepovertyheadcountratiointhesecond
(nexttopoorest)quintileincreasesby11percentagepoints.Inbothcountries,
higherfoodpricesleadtoaslightdecreaseinthepovertyheadcountinthe
poorestexpenditurequintile.Thisisbecauseeveninthepoorestgroupsthere
aresomehouseholdsthatarenetsellersandthereforegainfromthefoodprice
increase.Sincebeforethefoodpriceriseallhouseholdsinthepoorestquintile
inPakistanwerepoor,theheadcountratiodecreasesassoonasoneormoreof
thesehouseholdscrossesthepovertyline.
Households that remain below the poverty line are worse off with higher
food prices.InBangladeshthesimulatedricepriceriseleadstoan increase in the
intensity of poverty as measured by the poverty gap which
increasesfrom0.35to0.41(upperpovertyline)and0.25to0.32(lowerpoverty
line).Similarly,inPakistanthesimulatedwheatpriceincreaseresultsinarise in the
poverty gap from 0.17 to 0.18. Thus, high food prices clearly hurt the
pooresthouseholds.
Despitethepossibilityofsecondroundeffects,aconsiderableportion
ofthewelfarelosscausedbyfoodpriceinflationislikelytopersist— unless the
general equilibrium effects are significantly larger than second roundadjustments.Thatoutcomeisunlikely,giventhatthewageelasticities
of output prices in South Asia tend to be relatively low. Whether poverty
causedbyincreasingfoodpricesispermanentortransitorywilllargelydepend on whether
high food prices persist and for how long, and on how
governmentsrespond,intermsofsocialprotectionprogramsandotherpolicy measures.
TRADELIBERALIZATIONANDFOODPRICES
In principle, intraregional trade liberalization could mitigate food
price inflation. Discussions regarding the food crisis in South Asia have
largely ignored the regional dimension of food price inflation and the
possibilityofimprovingfoodsecuritybyliberalizingtrade.Incountriesthat
traditionallyrelyonfoodimports,regionaltradeliberalizationmightincrease
confidenceininternationalmarkets.
During the food crisis most countries in South Asia increased their
trade barriers instead of facilitating trade. Whileinanefforttocontrol
domestic food prices, most South Asian countries reduced import taxes, several
of them also introduced export control measures or even banned exports of
certain staples. These “beggarthyneighbor” type policies aggravated price
increases elsewhere, as seen in Afghanistan where wheat prices shot up after
Pakistan introduced an export ban, and in Bangladesh where India’s restrictions
on rice exports contributed to rice price inflation.
Exportbansalsoencouragedsmugglingwhileloweringeconomicreturnsfor
domesticfarmers.
TheSouthAsianFreeTradeArea(SAFTA)agreementaimsatincreasing intraregionaltradeviapartialtradeliberalization.Basedonformaltrade
flows, South Asia is one of the world’s least integrated regions. The SAFTA
agreementisanattempttoincreaseintraregionaltradethroughthegradual dismantling
of some tariff barriers, but it leaves out a large number of products
denominated as sensitive, and it does not address nontariff trade barriers.
Chapter 3 of this report uses a worldwide recursive dynamic
computablegeneralequilibriumtrademodeltoanalyzeSAFTA’spotentialfor increasing
intraregional trade and mitigating food price increases in South Asia.
ThefindingsshowthatSAFTA’spotentialforinfluencingdomesticfood
pricesinSouthAsiaislimited.Themodelsimulationsindicatethatglobal
restrictionsoncerealexportshadamuchsmallerimpactondomesticpricesin
SouthAsiathantheglobalaverage,mainlybecauseofSouthAsia’srelatively
limiteddependenceoninternationalmarkets.TheyalsosuggestthatSAFTA
hardlydampensdomesticpriceincreases,mainlybecauseofthelargenumber
of“sensitiveproducts”(negativelist)andtheabsenceofagreementsregarding
nontarifftradebarriersandsubsidiesinSAFTA.1
Tariff reductions
under SAFTA will not be enough to reduce informal trade in South Asia.
Official trade data are widely believed to grossly understate the
“true” size of intraSouth Asian trade, given the substantial
informaltradeflows.Indeedinformalimportsofwheatandwheatflourfrom
PakistanensuredamoreorlesscontinuingsupplyinAfghanistanduring2007 08
despitetheofficialexportbanimposedbyPakistan.Aninitialattemptto model informal
trade suggests that SAFTA has only a limited impact on
informaltradeflowsacrossallcountries.Tariffreductions,intheabsenceof other
institutional reforms and enforcement, would most likely have little impact on
illegal crossborder trade, especially between Pakistan and Afghanistan.
LESSONSLEARNEDANDTHEWAYFORWARD
Thefoodcrisisisbynomeansover.Domesticpricesofbothwheatandrice
remainhighthroughoutSouthAsia.Thereisgrowingagreementthatatwo track approach is
required, combining increased investments in safety nets
withmeasurestostimulatebroadbasedagriculturalproductivitygrowth,with
majoremphasisonthemajorfoodstaples.
The degree of price transmission is an important determinant of
consumerwelfare.Forobviouspoliticalandsocialreasons,mostSouthAsian
governmentsarelikelytocontinuetoseektoprotectconsumersagainstprice variability.
This requires careful management of price transmission through trade, pricing,
and stocking policies, supplemented by social protection programs.
Policies and programs for managing price transmission need to be
appropriately designed. Trade policies should encourage the operation of
theprivatesectorandnotrestrictexports.Pricingpoliciesmayincludelimited
subsidies targeted to the poor, but general control measures should be
avoided.Publicgrainreservesshouldbelimitedinsize,andaninternational coordinated
global food reserve—in which countries’ own reserves would
becomepartofalargerglobalreserve—deservesconsideration.
Protectingconsumers’welfareandmaximizingfoodsecurityinasustainable
andfiscallyaffordablewayisonlypossibleifsimultaneousattentionisgivento
appropriatesupplyresponsemeasuresthatprotectproducers’welfareaswell.
1
Thesesimulationresultsdonotmeanthatexportrestrictionsimposedbyindividual
countries do not matter. By restricting supplies, export restrictions can
seriously
augmentfoodpriceinflationinimportingcountriesthatimportalargeportionoftheir
foodsuppliesfromthecountriesthatimposedtheban.
Higher food prices are not
unequivocally bad and may provide new opportunities. Besides the potential
benefits to net selling households and
theireffectsonsupply,higherfoodpricescouldgenerateanumberofother benefits. In
South Asia, they provide an opportunity to policymakers to re examine the
complex system of inputoutput pricing interventions; reduce spending on input
subsidies and instead refocus public spending on investments to raise farm
productivity (irrigation, rural roads, electricity) as
wellasonimprovedsocialprotectionmeasures.Higherfoodpricesmayalso stimulate
innovative developments in food aid, in particular a shift from
traditionalfoodaidtofoodassistancethroughlocalfoodpurchasescombined
withcashtransfersandvouchers.Sustainedhigherfoodpricescouldalsohelp the
implementation of responsible international trade policies that benefit
lowincome countries, and help to reform developed countries’ agricultural
supportprogramsinawaythatmayremovetheremainingbarrierstoprogress
ontheWTODohatradenegotiations.
Thelongtermchallengetoproduceenoughfoodhasnotdisappeared. The
underlying problems remain of low stockpiles, rising demand mainly fuelled by
continuing population growth in developing countries, and flattening yield
growth. These problems are particularly relevant for South
Asia,giventheregion’shighpopulationgrowth.
RaisingproductivityisnecessarytoensureSouthAsia’sfoodsecurity.
Giventhatmostproductivelandisalreadyundercultivation,futureincreases
in agricultural production in the region will need to be based on yield
increases.Becauseworldpricesofenergyandfertilizerareexpectedtoremain
substantiallyhigherthanbefore,yieldincreasesaretheonlysustainableway to
reconcile higher input costs and farmers’ incentives with low and stable
consumerpricesofwheatandrice.
Yieldincreasesseementirelyfeasiblegiventhesubstantialyieldgapsin
SouthAsianagriculture.Despiteafewimportantexceptions,theimpactof
higherpricesoncropyieldshasbeenlimitedsofar.Toraiseyieldsrequiresa combination
of technical interventions and socioeconomic policies and measures. But besides
technology transfer, policymakers should ensure that the global economic crisis
does not jeopardize public investment in agricultural research and rural
infrastructure. Governments must also allow price incentives to reach farmers,
The should ensure that adequate mechanismsareinplaceforsupplyingqualityinputsataccessiblepricesand
thatfarmershaveappropriatemarketingopportunities.Inthiscontextpublic
spendingonirrigation,ruralroads,andelectricityiscrucial.